Friday, March 28, 2008

Caste Discrimination Translated into Ethnic Cleansing in this Divided Bleeding Geopolitics

Palash Biswas

Caste Discrimination is translated into ethnic cleansing in this divided geopolitics!

Kolkata Intelligentsia delebratly defends CPIM as they brand the Dandakaranya Refugees landed in Marichjhanpi as tresspasser Bangladeshi Nationals in a protected Forest Zone, Tiger Project. Mind you, Marichjhanpi never have been under protected Forest or Tiger project. Suman Mukhopaddhay of Teesta parer Britanto(play) and Herbert (film,written by Nabarun bhattacharya), refuses to consider Marichjhanpi a case of Ethnic Cleansing. I have seen his elitist subversion of the protagonist Bgaharu of the Debesh Roy Novel. Bengali Caste Hindu media and Intelligentsia call Nandigram killings a Genocide as caste Hindu Politics of Power Dominance as well as Resistance involved.Though, the victims happen to be either ST SC or OBC and Muslims! But Marichjahanpi was, all in all, a case of Political Betrayal by the communists who got them ousted of Dandyakarany Refugee colonies and Camps to constitute a favourable Vote bank to capture power. Communist Movement in Bengal got momentum with Refugee vote Bank. Thus, the Communists never spoke against continuous presecution of Minorities in East Bengal nor did try to stop the Refugee Influx at any point of time. Not only this, Communist leaders including Basu, have been claiming to fight for Rehabilitation of refugees. They protested Bidhan Roy`s initiative to send bengali refugees out of Bengal . Samar Mukherjee and jyoti Basu had been writing to the Centre and State governments to rehbiliatate the East Bengal refugees in Sundarvanas from the very beginning! They never mentioned Forest area or Tiger Project at that time! More over,Jyoti Basu, Ram Chatterjee and Kiranmoy Nanda with other prominent leaders visietd country wide with an appeal, West Benagl with a five coroer population with ten coroer hands would welcome the dalit Bengali refugees and they will be rehabiliated in West Bengal. As Basu took over in 1977, Ram Chatterjee and Nanda with other leaders visited Mana Camp and Malakan Giri to call the refugees to settle in Sundarva. They went there with messages from the Chief Minister! Earlier Basu himself addressed refugee leaders including satish Mandal in Bhilai.

My father Pulin Babu, with his experience as a communist refugee leader in West bengal and Orissa and Peasant Leader in Dhimri Block peasants Insurrection in nainital, as a rescuer in Assam and North East understood the betrayal game and some how convinced the North India Refugees of UP, Bihar, Assam and Rajsthan that dangers ahead and the communists would betray. As the communists never helped the refugeees in these states and they are in better status, they could not be trapped. Not a single refugee landed in Marichjhanpi from North India excluding MP.
At that time , I was a student in DSB college in naninital and have been involved with Chipko Movement. I quoted forest laws and explained Environment significance of Sundarvana as my father decided to oppose the campaign actively. I talked face to face Satish Mand , the man behind Marichjhanpi movementright in the Mana Camp, Chhattish Garghwhere the Marichjhanpi refugees retuned back empty handed losing near and dear ones in Marichjhanpi. Satish Mandal said that my father would have been killed in Mana camp as he spoke against such a campaign and communists. security forces saved his life. He and his associates regretted and accepted that it was a blunder. They explained how the communists mobilised the Marichjhanpi movement centred in and around all the major five refugee camps in MP and entire Dandakarany resettlement spanning four states MP (united), Orissa, Andhra and maharashtra!

Another fact remains, only,yes only Dandakarany resetlled Refugees from Malkan GiRi of Orissa, Andhra and Maharashtra with refugees stranded in Five Major camps of United MP landed in Marichjhanpi. Resetlled refugees lived in those colonies since fifties while the refugees form all those five camps crosed the border during and befrore Riots of 1964 in East Bengal. They were not Bangladeshi nationals, as the Ruling Hegemony with its media and intellegentsia have been claiming all these years.Branding the refugess as Bangladeshi Nationals or escaped masses from refugee camps justify the Eviction drive and translate the Genocide as a political blunder only. This is syastematic subvertion freinds!

I am amazed why a writer like Amitabh Ghosh could not care to cross check his information as he described Marichjhanpi under tiger project! He, though unlike other Caste Hindu intellectuals described it a Genocide. Utpal Dutta wrote a drama at that time to justify the genocide- Chakranta. Media flashed this Plot theory with branding the bonafied Indian citizens as bangladeshi Nationals. Different stories were afloat like extrmest camp and armed training and popular CPIM concept of CIA and foreign hand to dislodge the communist Government. Left Front partner RSP held the base in that area and local panchayats were captured by them. RSP activists helped the refugees. Basu called them in the Writers and directed them to detach with the refugees and the Party Machinery led by late Pramod Dasgupta hatched the eviction plan. before blocked Subhash chakrabarti visited Marichjhanpi and offered the refugees CPIM umbrella. But satish mandal refuged considering RSP and Janata dal cooperation. Janata Dal was the ruling party in the centre.JD MP Kashikanta Moitra was with them. Had the refugees joined CPIM, it would have been a different story as it has always been in thousands of refugee colonies. You may see the RSP leaders speaking out as Eye witness in Tortured Humanity, the Rights alert film!

Mind you, before partition all the three interim governments were headed by Muslims- Fazlul haq, Najibullah and Sohrawardi.Only Shyama Prasad Mukherjee was a member in Haq ministery . Otherwise Jogendra Nath mandal or Kumud Bihari Mallick were the personalities on centrestage. Muslims in East Bengal were dead against partition. They wanted undivided Bengal.And bengal was the centrestage of national dalit Movement with mandal in helms. Shyama Prasasd Mukherjee had said, if not India, Bengal must be divided as Caste Hindus were wary of Muslim dalit Combination . This combnitation was broken with partition. The dalit base devasted and dalit movement sabotaged. Dalits were evicted out of their home in East bengal and scattered countrywide. marichjhanpi revived the danger of Dalit Population concentration in Bengal once agian and ruling brahminical Marxists aborted it mercilessly with Marichjhanpi Genocide. thus, the Ruling Caste Hindus with all the bogus Marxism, secularism and progressive posture kept mum on Marichjhanpi!

Anu jalais told me that the problem all along this subcontinent roots in Caste Discrimination and the Hegemony system. She agrred with my contention that it was a demographic readjustmant case and said this interesting. Even the then Police Super of North 24 parganas, the officer in chareg of the marichjhanpi genocide discuses the role played by Ram Chatterjee and other left leaders. Just see the film, HUMANITY TORTURED! Now samanat is also iconised like runu Guha Niyogi. Niyogi justified the Repression and killings during seventies in his book, AAmi Sada Aami Kalo. Samanto writes column in the Satesman as well as Paschim Banga, a WB GOV mag. The ex DGP writes on topics spanning police reforms to revolutionary activities in colonial India. Even Amiya samanta, accepts, had the Marichjhanpi refugees not been Dalits they would not be evicted so mercilessly. He also acceptes the facts of Food Blocked. All Eye Witnesses and all evidences are there! Who would stand for justice? Human Rights? For the deprived, persecuted, marginaliged, totured and killed Dalit Refugees?

All the Dalit Leaders and intellectuals shed tears on Marichjhanpi genocide! They oppose Citizenship act. They are associated with refugee Movement and different Dalit orgs. But they could not bring the War criminals to justice! They could not launch a Political or non Political movement. They claim to know everything! What they did all these thirty years? Just tried their best to get maximum favour of the ruling Hegamony or simply a stautus in Prliament , assembly or pachayat or a reserved post, promotion! They licked the Bottom of the Ruling Hegemony! My foot!
The partition victim Dalit East Bengal refugees- evicted from homeland to accomodate Caste Hindu Brahminical Hegemony with transfer of Power from apartheid generator British clonial rulers, deprived of human and civil rights, mother tongue and citizenship, targeted nationwide as branded as bangladeshi foriegn national thanks to Citizenship Amendment Act passed by Indian Ruling Class represented by all kinds of left, centrist and Right ideologies and parties and finally facing nationwide deportation drive thanks to brahmins of Bengal led by Defacto Prime Minister Pranab Mukherjee and Hindutva forces led by Sangh Pariwar and shiv sena -should thank Mr Prabhu Chawla , the editor- in - chief of India Today to publish a special report in India Today Bengali on Marichjhanpi Genocide, coinciding with 30th year of the first dress rehearsal of Genocide culture launched by the Regemented so called marxist ruling hegemony in West Bengal.

It might sound something very amusing to welcome a gesture so insignificant in these days of Electronic channels, media boom and information explosion. Well, in North as well as south India, the resettled Dalit East Bengal refugees enjoy the support of local population. In Orissa, while Naveen Patnaik BJP plus BJD ruling combination tried to deport the Noakhali Partition victims resttled in Ram Nagar, Mahakal Para area near Paradip port, Oria speaking local residents constituted an Utkal Bangiya Suraksha committee to defend the helpless people. Local residents, Media and political parties jointly stalled the deportation move there. Though the struggle is going on as the Refugges resettled there in early fifties find their names missing in Voters` List. Ration cards are also stand cancelled.

In United Uttar Pradesh,where I originally belong as I was born in a refugee colony in Udham Singh Nagar (Nainital), the local population always stood by dalit Bengali Refugees. My father late Pulin kumar Biswas worked for the refugees lifelong. He was the President of All India Udvastu ( Refugee) committee. He as a Communist Leader led the Dhimri Block Peasants` Revolt in 1958 in the Terai of Nainital. The insurrection was repressed brutally by joint forces of third jat Regiment, Police and PAC. CH Charan singh was the Home Minister in UP then. Communist Party of India with General secretary Comrade PC Joshi disowned the movement as they betrayed Telengana. In UP, no one could a single instance of confrontation between bengali refugees and other communities. In Terai of Nainital, Pilbhit, Bareilly and Rampur a few corore partion victims Sikh and Punjabies as well as Bengalies live side by side with a bond of unbreakable fraternity and cooperation for six decades. My father was elected un opposed the Vice President Of Terai Cooperative Commitee in mid sixties with local SDM as President by virtue of his post. I want to emphasise that at that point, sikhs and punjabies were more powerful, more dominent and majority in number. bengali Dalit refugees were minority plus economically very weak. But the chemistry of Unity is working since the first day. The spirit of peasant movement works even after the deaths of all the leaders including my father and his comrades. We always enjoyed excellent relations with Hills. ND Tiwari and KC Pant became National Leaders with our help only.

In 2001, as UP was divided and BJP took over as the ruling party in the new state Uttaranchal. Chief Minister Nityanand Swami and His government branded all Bengali dalit refugees living there since 1952 as foreign nationals. Bengali refugees launched an unprecedented movement supported by all opposition political parties, communities, markets and media. This is the only occassion while West Bengal, its government, ruling front, media and people supported us. Because, we could convince Buddhadev Bhattacharya, the new Chief Minister that provided the dalit refugees were evicted out of Uttaranchal as planned by Sangh pariwar, they would come to West Bengal without any notice and Left Front had to face similar crisis as Marichjhanpi. Contrary to dandakaranya People the uttarakhandi Bengalies are more united and they might not repeat marichjhanpi genocide once again.
Finally, Uttaranchal BJP government had to give in.

This is all India scenerio barring spordiac clashes between tribals of Chhattish Gargh and Orissa. Of course, entire North East, particularly Assam, Tripura and Manipur showcase a different equation. And it is due to the identity crisis of natinalities there. In mainland , all Dalit Bengali refugees supported the nationality movement as in Uttarakhand, Jharkhand and Chhattish gargh. Only Maharashtra and Mumbai are different cases where all North Indians are branded unwanted and the dominent Sangh Pariwar target all Bengali speaking people branding them as bangladeshi Nationals.

Here you are! In West Bengal, the Caste Hindu Ruling Hegemony never allows any space for dalit Bengali Refugees in any sphere of life. The irony is that a refugee, Dr man Mohan singh becomes prime Minister, another refugee Lal Krishna Adwani Deputy Prime Minister while another refugee Jyoti Basu ruled Bengal for two decades and a half while all dalit partition victims of east Bengal are branded as foreign nationals.

Mind you, it is India Today of Non bengali origin published the story. Not even any revolutionary little mag or sanhati.com or so called different, progressive and secular Bengali Intelligentsia highlighted the Genocide for long thirty years. For example, Mahashweta Devi had been active as a creative writer for so long. She wrote so many things on Insurrections of all kind and on also Naxalbari. She is writing daily on nandigram and singur. She writes on Rizwanur and Taslima so frequently! Why she could not take over the marichjhanpi issue in past thirty years? Sunil Gangopadhyaya, the Ruling Hegemony cultural head at present and the Shikhandi President of sahitya academy of India never had been a Marxist in the days of Tebhaga and food movement. Sunil along with Sandipan and Shakti ruled Kolkata in sixties with anarchist posture. Sunil visited USA during that period and befriended with Ginsberg. Sunil did the excellent work lifetime during Marichjahnpi blocked . He reported exclusively for Anand bazaer as Niranjan Haldar did. But, Sunil became a Marxist very soon and kept MUM all these years. rights Alert India could not get him face camera for its documentary on Marichjhanpi. Mr jagadish Chandra Mandal, worthy son of Maha Pran Jogendra Nath Mandal, wrote a Book, marichjahnpi in Bengali. Ananda Bazar published the review with lacs of circulation. But Bengal could not find a single voice to represent the massacred indigenous people and the plight of partition victims all these days.

An eminent Activist, a former associate of Sunil gango, the vice President of Bhasha Shaheed Smarak Committee, Ratan Basu Majumdar claimed that Bengali Intelligentsia did not know about the massacre! Is it so? Even after Anu Jalius`s EPW article, a few books on marichjhanpi, so much matterial available on net thanks to reasearchers lake Anu and Ross Mallick, a very significant novel like Hungry Tide by an eminent writer like Amitabh Ghosh, Sunil`s writings before three decades and the documentary, Humanity Tortured by Rights Alert India? Ratanda told me mahasheta devi would certainly write! has she written? I have been a keen reader of Mahashwetya Sahitya for almost three decades. I have been associated with his Mag Bhasha Bandhan, in which I could not get any space for those five corore Dalit bangali refugees scattered all over India!

While the Citizenship Amendment Bill was published on net, I passed personally the copies to top CPIM leaders. All of them assured they would oppose. While the bill was passed undebated in both houses of Parliament as only Dr Manmohan Singh,then a Rajya Shabha memebr fro Assam and general Shankar Roy Chowdahury urgued theat the refugees form east bengal should get Indian Citizenship. Dr Singh forgot that. NDA Home minister lK adwani presented the Bill. Pranab Mukherjee was the chairman of the standing committee on the Bill. All refugee orgs and individuals and activists opposed and communicated to Mukherjee. Mukherjee did not call any of us. Rather he boasted before a Refugee deputation that had he been the Home Minister he would have got deported all foreign National bengali refugees. So, he is executing his plan nowadays. Kanti Biswas, then a cabinet minister and Upen kisku a ST minister claimed on phone that CPIM opposed the Bill. We all know the reality.

Forget Marichjhanpi! More than Twenty Lac people in west bengal got their names deleted from voters`s List as they have been branded as Bangladeshi Nationals. Thousands have been dumped in jail in Krishnanagar, Burdwan, katoa, Nadia and Howrah. Thosand and thousand absconding. No news appeared in Kolkata Media. No intellectual protested.

I myself gave Mahashwetadi personally all relevent documents on Citizenship and Refugee Problems. She just told that she could not take over all the issues. She commented, Palash, you have to launch this movement!

In such a background, ANshuman Bhowmic has done a marvellous job as a jounalist.

Thursday, March 27, 2008

Administrative Crackdown on BESU Students

Bengal Engineering And Science University (BESU), Shibpur, Howrah-711 103

FACTSHEET in chronological order:

07.09.2007:
A notice ( memo no. RDO-2/1387) had been issued by the registrar where it was notified that four final year students (UG) and six 3rd year students (UG) were suspended and instructed to vacate their respective hostels with immediate effect for an indefinite period of time. But in the aforementioned notice, lots of irregularities have been found, which are mentioned below:

· It is clearly mentioned in the notice that inquiries against the students alleged to have committed misdemeanors, were pending. Then, we would like to know, how, without proper inquiry, were the 10 students slapped with such harsh punishment?

· We have found that one of the accused students viz. Tanmoy Chatterjee (3rd yr. Metallurgy) was not present in the university campus on the date on which alleged incident took place. He had in fact, gone to visit his friend’s ailing mother, at Peerless Hospital. Then how did his name crop up in the notice?

So it is explicit that the accused 10 students had been wrongly framed and suspended on the basis of some fabricated allegations. We are amazed and upset at this sort of bias on the part of the authority.

12.12. 2007:
" A second year student (U.G) named Afaz-Uddin Ahmed of the Dept. of Information Technology is fomenting trouble & violence in the University campus for the last one year. He, with the help of some of his batch mates is explicitly trying to disturb the peace & harmony of the University campus by infusing dirty politics in the affairs related to the students & inciting violence in the University campus, thus denting the integrity among the students. It had been reported to the concerned authority that he was found to behave in the most unacceptable manner and even has the audacity to manhandle some of his seniors. Presently he has taken his grudge to such an extent that he is threatening his own batch mates of dire consequences if they do not pay their “allegiance” to him. Now he has become so desperate that he is even trying to scare them by threatening that he will take “revenge” by waging his animosity against their families. It has been heard that a guardian of his batch mate has received threatening calls from an anonymous phone number, which is unprecedented in the history of this 150 year old institution. There is no denying the fact that his activities are unbecoming of a student of such a reputed institution.

We had lodged several complaints against him to the concerned authority, but unfortunately all have gone unheeded. If he is testing our patience, we would like to make it clear that we will no longer remain as silent victims of his inhuman acts. It is unfortunate to inform you that his motive of gaining narrow political mileage is explicitly getting the patronage of some of the office bearers of BESU, as found in yesterday night’s incident at hostel 9.But unfortunately the University authority is trying to overlook his heinous activities because of his outside political support. " (From a mass petition by the students)
When we drew the attention of our faculty members to this matter and submitted a mass petition to the Dean of Students (PICSA) on 12.12.2007, the authority came under pressure to act and constituted a disciplinary committee. But on the very day (13th December, 2007), Students’ Federation of India staged a rally and intentionally fomented panic among the students. And the result was imposition of section 144 in the campus, a black day for us. The “Afaaz” issue, thus, died down.

19.3.2008:
Three 2nd year students returning to their hostels at around 10 p.m. were ragged and racially abused by few boarders of “Wolfenden Hall”, as they were natives from outside West Bengal. They were physically assaulted and two 2nd year students sustained head injuries. Police forces were called in to control the situation. However, the boarders of “Wolfenden Hall” continued to resort to violent means in spite of the presence of police and faculty members. Two of the Wolfenden boarders were caught red handed with hockey sticks (it is to be noted that there is no hockey team in our university) by the faculty members. But, on insistence of Prof. Bhawani Prasad Mukhopadhay, the two were released with no charges being levied against them.

20.3.2008:
In the evening, party cadres brutally assaulted few students at the first gate of the university in front of R.A.F. SFI supporters helped them by pointing out the targets. When the students appealed to the R.A.F to take action, they resorted to indiscriminate “lathicharge” on the students. They even entered Richardson Hall without the permission of the hostel superintendent and assaulted the boarders, including a physically handicapped student. More than twenty students were seriously injured. The same act was repeated in Sengupta as well as Sen Halls. The dual policy adopted by the R.A.F. was apparent from the ease with which cadres were roaming freely and threatening us in the presence of R.A.F. In the mean time SFI supporters attacked 2nd year hostels. The 2nd year students were so terrified that they sought our help. We took them to our hostels, called our University doctors and provided them with First Aid. Strangely, the authority’s idea of assistance was an order to vacate the hostels near midnight. Buses were provided to transport us to the Howrah station. We narrated the ordeal of the 2nd year students to police. They assured us that the 2nd year students would be able to reach their hostels. So we boarded the bus provided by the authority. But unfortunately when we reached Howrah Station we came to know that the hapless 2nd year students were arrested by police charging them of loitering in the campus after 10-30 pm.

You can surely understand that we, the students have become victims of SFI-Authority-Police nexus whose sole motive is to de-stabilize our esteemed Institution. Our very existence in the University campus is at stake. We would like to vehemently protest against the barbaric treatment given to the ordinary students.

24.03.2008:
Students were put under virtual house arrest, and their free movement was restricted by the police. They even threatened students of dire consequences, which included threatening them with initiation of legal proceedings and disrupting their careers, for no valid reason.

The press was not allowed to enter the campus and report the incidents occurring inside. Even the students were not allowed to go near the press and express their views. This constitutes a gross violation of human rights.

We would like to appeal to you to bring this to the attention of the nation at large and help us to bring the offenders to justice.

With warm regards,
Students (U.G)
BESU,Shibpur

SIBPUR BESU UPDATE

1. The Sibpur BESU students are continuing their sit-in at Metro Channel, Esplanade. Almost everybody has submitted a blank sheet in the examinations. Many have again written "Save BESU from becoming a Nandigram".

On Thursday, March 27, they are calling for solidarity from students, teachers, engineers and other intellectuals. They have obtained formal police permission for a structure from 4-8 pm at Metro Channel, Esplanade.

2. The authorities at BESU have opened the sealed packets containing scripts, before delivery to the examiners, with the motivation of picking out victims. Because the confidentiality of the examination process has been compromised, the teachers at BESU, after a council meeting, declared the examinations to be null and void.

Some samples of what happened :

Moloy (name changed), after being assaulted reached the Registrar to complain against the assailants. He was still covered with blood. The Registrar handed him a copy of a complaint against himself, filed by the assailants to the effect that Moloy had assaulted them.

Subir, Pankaj, Joy and others (names changed) complained to the VC when he came to their hostel that they had been cruelly assaulted. The VS smiled sweetly and said , "Why are you making up stories? Nobody assaulted you."

Both of these characters have been tireless in telling students and guardians that the students should join the SFI (students' outfit of the ruling communists of West Bengal) and all trouble would stop.

There should be a Citizens' Enquiry into these alleged misdemeanors of the Vice Chancellor and the Registrar of BESU.

Friday, March 21, 2008

Five Years In Iraq:Iraqis and Americans Offer Perspectives on the War


Karen DeYoung
Washington Post ,Wednesday, March 19, 2008

For a majority of Americans, today marks the fifth anniversary of the start of an Iraq war that was not worth fighting, one that has cost thousands of lives and more than half a trillion dollars. For the Bush administration, however, it is the first anniversary of an Iraq strategy that it believes has finally started to succeed.

It has been about a year since Army Gen. David H. Petraeus arrived to command U.S. forces in Iraq, Ambassador Ryan C. Crocker took over as the chief U.S. diplomat, and the military deployed 30,000 more troops to protect and rebuild neighborhoods.

Officials now running the U.S. effort express frustration that the gains wrought by their new political, security and economic policies -- in particular, sharply reduced violence -- are continually weighed against the first four years of the war, when Iraq unraveled in insurgency and sectarian strife.

"I came to Washington to describe what we're doing," Charles P. Ries, Crocker's senior deputy in charge of reconstruction and the Iraqi economy, said during a visit last week. "At almost every meeting, somebody wants me to describe what we used to do. . . . I know why people raise these questions, but I don't feel it's something I can speak to. The times were different then."

Today's policy is fundamentally different from the impatient mind-set of 2003, in both lowered U.S. expectations and a less imperious approach to dealing with Iraqi authorities. "In those days," Ries said, "we decided what [the Iraqis] needed, and we built it." Today, he said, Iraqis are asked what they want, and then told that while the United States will help, they will have to pay for most of it themselves.

Yet as the administration requests additional war funding and calls for a pause in promised troop withdrawals, some question its right to a second chance. "Like a tourniquet," the troop increase "has stopped the bleeding," Sen. Jack Reed (D-R.I.), a former Army Ranger and senior member of the Armed Services Committee, reported last week after his 11th trip to Iraq. What he has not seen, Reed said, are the surgery and recovery that would begin to heal the wound that Iraq has become. And even U.S. officials acknowledge that the "surge" has not led to the political reconciliation the administration had hoped for.

Others see the past year's successes as fragile and reversible, and less consequential than the pain that preceded them. "I think they have it righter than they ever have before," Daniel P. Serwer, an Iraq expert with the U.S. Institute of Peace, said of the administration. "But the fact is that those four other years did exist, and they condition a lot of what can and cannot happen now. There's a history here, there's a lot of blood and guts on the floor -- literally."

The White House tends to dismiss such longer memories. While it recognizes the inclination to "relitigate the past" when a milestone such as the fifth anniversary is reached, National Security Council spokesman Gordon Johndroe said, "our focus is on the way ahead and making sure that the current situation and the future situation gets better."

In addition to new directions on the ground in Iraq, officials point to a newly effective structure designed to avoid the kind of ad hoc decision-making that led to early bureaucratic gridlock and mistakes, such as decrees dissolving the Iraqi army and banning Baath Party members from government jobs. President Bush's appointment last spring of Lt. Gen. Douglas E. Lute as deputy national security adviser for Iraq and Afghanistan has "helped streamline the process and made sure that there is . . . a senior-level official who can devote his full, undivided attention" to the subject, Johndroe said.

The once-bickering State Department and Pentagon are reporting new levels of cooperation. Diplomats who recall Donald H. Rumsfeld's insistence that the Defense Department control all aspects of early postwar policy note approvingly that it was his successor as defense secretary, Robert M. Gates, who recently called on Congress to increase the State Department's budget.

Many U.S. officials participating in the new efforts talk about those years as though they belonged to another administration. "We weren't here five years ago," said one who, like several interviewed for this article, spoke on the condition of anonymity about past policy on the grounds that it would undermine the present.

"In the early days, they had an idea of something, a plan, of how it was going to be," the official said. "They would remove Saddam, and democracy would flower. They took this plan and rammed it down into the reality of Iraq, which nobody understood. What did they know about Iraq? Who were they listening to?" In the past year, the official said, "there has been a coming to grips across the board with Iraqi reality."

One of the more troublesome realities is that Iraqi leaders have been slow to take advantage of the "breathing space" that the troop increase was supposed to create. The administration has often noted that Washington and Baghdad operate on different clocks, with the U.S. timetable for demonstrable progress running far faster than its Iraqi counterpart. In an interview last week, Petraeus, the U.S. military commander, acknowledged that "no one" in the U.S. and Iraqi governments "feels that there has been sufficient progress by any means in the area of national reconciliation" or in the provision of basic public services.

In congressional testimony scheduled for early next month, both Petraeus and Crocker are expected to make the case that enough forward movement has been made to justify continuing the current strategy, and to warn that an abrupt withdrawal of U.S. troops could jeopardize the gains of the past year.

But while a strong congressional appearance by the two men last September quieted talk of funding cutoffs and brought a brief rise in public attention, their upcoming testimony appears to have sparked little anticipation.

As the administration struggles to focus on Iraq's future, it is competing with a presidential race locked in debate about how the war began and how to end it, a Democratic Congress determined to fight over every additional dollar, and a weary, distracted public.

Indeed, once a top public concern, Iraq has been muscled aside by the economy and the political campaigns. In a survey released last week by the Pew Research Center, more people knew the names of the head of the Federal Reserve Board and the president of Venezuela than knew the approximate number of U.S. casualties in Iraq.

Some public views about the situation in Iraq have eased over the past year. But others, including baseline judgments about the war itself, have hardly budged. In the latest Washington Post-ABC News poll, nearly two-thirds said the war was not worth waging. Less than half, 43 percent, think the United States is making significant progress, and majorities continue to judge the war's benefits as not worth its costs.

Polling director Jon Cohen contributed to this report.

Friday, March 07, 2008

Cities of the past and the future

Le Monde diplomatique
-----------------------------------------------------

March 2008

THIRD GOLDEN AGE FOR IZMIR

Cities of the past and the future
___________________________________________________________

What would it mean if Turkey became the first country in the
region to host an expo? And how did the expo begin? Marina Da
Silva asked Vicente Gonzales Loscertales

by Marina Da Silva
___________________________________________________________

There are two kinds of expo: world and international. World
expos run for six months, are held every five years,
concentrate on a general theme and transform a large part of
the host city. The 350-hectare site requires massive urban
reconstruction to improve its design; participating countries
can build their own pavilions which, according to the rules,
must then be demolished, unless their architectural value
leads the host country to negotiate their preservation.

International expos - held between world expos - are much
less expensive. They cover only 25 hectares and last a
maximum of three months. The pavilions are built by the host
city, and smaller scale construction and infrastructure is
required. What is produced can be recycled, allowing host
cities to recover part of their investment quickly and
acquire development assets in line with their own strategic
plans. These exhibitions have specialised themes. The first
expo of the 21st century will be held in Shanghai in 2010 on
the theme "Better City, Better Life".

The concept of expos grew out of the expansion of
industrialisation: empire-building nations wanted to show
that they were at the forefront of modernity and material
progress, capable of transforming nature and controlling the
world. The first "world expo" was London's Great Exhibition
in 1851. From then on they evolved in parallel with political
and social developments. Initially, they were meetings where
states could parade their industrial products, innovations
and power. After the second world war a new idea developed
and the aim became more general, encompassing social and
cultural achievements.

Rivalry between France and Britain in the 19th century led to
an increase in the number of expos. The first expo in Paris
was in 1855, and then again in 1867, 1878, 1889 and 1900,
with the last large one in 1937. The appearance of modern
Paris owes much to them - the Eiffel Tower was built for the
exhibition commemorating the centenary of the French
Revolution, the Grand and Petit Palais were built for the
1900 exhibition, and the Palais de Chaillot and the Palais de
Tokyo for that of 1937.

Historical context can have a significant impact on the
exhibitions. As Vicente Gonzales Loscertales, secretary
general of the International Exhibitions Bureau, explains:
"The 1937 exhibition was marked by the extreme political
tension of the period - German and Italian fascism versus
Soviet communism. This was a real pre-war exhibition and a
very militant one; in the throes of civil war, Spain's
pavilion mobilised many anti-fascist intellectuals and
included Picasso's Guernica. But the exhibitions are prepared
far in advance. In the early stages there is always an
impression of normality and then all of a sudden a crisis
blows up."

At the Seville expo in 1992 the scheduled pavilion for the
USSR became the Russian Federation pavilion, and then that of
the Commonwealth of Independent States. The Yugoslav
Federation pavilion disintegrated like the country. Germany
started with two pavilions and ended with one.

Popular acclaim

In the 1990s the concept went through a crisis. Some began to
wonder whether these events still had a purpose; others asked
whether the idea remained valid when globalisation proposed a
united world dominated by capitalism and multinational
corporations.

But the number of applicants wanting to organise exhibitions
kept growing and the public attended in ever greater numbers.
The Seville exhibition in 1992 had 41 million visitors in six
months, four times more than Disneyland Paris that year. The
expo in Hanover in 2000 had 19 million visitors in five
months - almost double the number visiting the Millennium
Dome in London that year.

Loscertales accepts that the concept had to adapt. To give it
modern political value, millions of visitors had to be
attracted by large themes: food, health, sustainable
development. The applicant country chooses the theme, a major
factor in deciding whether an application is accepted: themes
high on the international agenda are in favour. The
exhibition in Hanover took up the issues of the Rio
conference on the environment and the UN's Agenda 21. And the
themes promoted at Aichi in Japan in 2005 (nature's wisdom)
and Saragossa in 2008 (water and the sustainable development
of cities) were taken from the UN's millennium objectives.

The expos went beyond government to include NGOs, companies
and cities. Loscertales argues that these exhibitions have
become a powerful forum for dialogue, giving people access to
important international debates. Their perspective is not
only political in power but also in the way that they take
into consideration the cultural development of each country,
respecting civilisations, identities and religions. They are
a dialogue between civilisations, not a clash.

States, not cities, apply to be hosts, as part of their
development priorities. Although investment by host cities
might be disproportionate, Loscertales says the exhibitions
encourage economic activity and generate revenue. Investment
is not wasted. When they are well designed, they transform
and modernise a country. Lisbon hosted the 1998 exhibition
because Portugal had decided to modernise its capital - the
exhibition was just a pretext. The city was extended
eastwards, its transport system improved and the urban area
increased, as did tourist revenue. The operation cost the
state /-500m ($729m) but it has provided much more in return.
Loscertales claims expos improve infrastructure and generate
considerable money, which can be invested in the social
sector.

The two candidate cities for the 2015 world expo, Izmir
(formerly Smyrna) and Milan, are proposing important themes:
health for Izmir and food for Milan. In Turkey's case, an
enormous effort is under way to improve public health and so
the theme is health for all. "Milan is a large, developed
western European city and a centre for design and Italian
industry. Izmir is a modern and dynamic Mediterranean, almost
Middle Eastern, city with a great historical tradition, and
is a centre of Hellenic and Byzantine culture, creating a
very open city... it borders a turbulent region," says
Loscertales.

There is great dynamism in the Turkish economy, along with
both modernisation and a rise in religious feeling. Turkey is
a member of both Nato and the Organisation of the Islamic
Conference. It is also an EU candidate country, a moderate
political partner with a liberal economy and a vast market.
If the exhibition is held there, Turkey will be the first
country in the region to host such an event. For Loscertales,
Milan is the safe bet but Izmir is a gamble on the future,
opening the door to a country that should be made welcome.
Visitors from across the world would be attracted to an
exhibition at the crossroads of civilisations and cultures.

The decision will be taken by the 140 member states of the
International Exhibitions Bureau after a secret ballot and
the result announced on 31 March.
________________________________________________________

Marina Da Silva is a journalist



Translated by Morag Young


________________________________________________________

ALL RIGHTS RESERVED © 1997-2008 Le Monde diplomatique

High rise, low spirits

Le Monde diplomatique
-----------------------------------------------------

March 2008

NO LIFE OF THEIR OWN AND NO LIFE TO GIVE

High rise, low spirits
___________________________________________________________

How did the tower block come to dominate the imaginations first
of the moneyed, then of architects and planners, and then the
skylines of cities worldwide?

by Thierry Paquot
___________________________________________________________

Tower blocks came in with the new construction techniques of
the later 19th century - metal frames, reliable lifts,
telephones - and with the desire of wealthy firms for
symbolic edifices to attract the envy of all. The world's
first proper high-rise building, at 40 metres, was erected in
New York in 1868, the second in Minneapolis, and the third in
Chicago.

The tower was capitalism on the rise made visible, a symbol
constantly outdated as more powerful enterprises commanded
ever-higher towers to appease the appetites of captains of
industry and high finance; they wanted their tower, their
seat of power, their commercial and public image. There's
something childish in this insatiable one-upmanship, although
there are architects who still see the 19th century tower as
the 21st century future.

But today's real challenge lies in developing an architecture
that moves with the times as the city evolves, and can deal
with people's expectations of wellbeing and environmental
quality. The first urgent steps must be towards housing for
all - those sleeping under bridges, families now poorly
housed. We need new standards and a new urban geography for
social housing. This calls for courageous new approaches in
funding, allocating housing and planning. Why not involve
future tenants in the construction of their homes?

High-rise buildings won't help. Their rents are high so they
remain in the luxury range. They offer no public space: life
revolves around lifts and the need for home deliveries. They
are vertical impasses such as those described by Paul
Virilio (1). They don't offer better office space either
(their air-conditioned universe is statistically proven to
provoke certain illnesses). After 9/11, World Trade Centre
businesses found offices in smaller units chiefly in New
Jersey; apart from occasional nostalgia for the Manhattan
scene, everybody was happier.

Still many prominent architects, with the real estate lobby
behind them, believe without proof that high-rise buildings
can resolve the land problem (which might be true in part),
improve densities (not proven), reduce energy needs (the data
is contradictory) and contribute to the community (how is not
clear).

At Mipim, the 2007 international real estate fair in Cannes,
visitors admired the proposals for Moscow's Federation Tower
(448m, delivery in 2010), Warsaw's Zlota 44 (54 floors), and
New York's Liberty Tower (541m) and New York Times Building
(228m). There were others for Dubai (over 800m) and Paris,
Nexity's Granite tower by Christian de Portzamparc, the
Generali by Valode and Pistre, and Thom Mayne's 300-metre
Unibail. And in London there was Renzo Piano's 300-metre
London Bridge Tower. All of this can only be explained by
corporate arrogance. As far back as 1936 Le Corbusier evoked
the possibility of a 2,000-metre tower for Paris. Only the
Japanese have gone that far to date, with a 4,000-metre tower
on the drawing board, and a 2,004-metre pyramid designed to
accommodate 700,000 residents and 800,000 office workers.

No life to give

The American architect Frank Lloyd Wright condemned the tower
phenomenon in 1930; skyscrapers, he said, had no life of
their own and no life to give, having received none at their
conception. They rise above a landscape without regard for
their surroundings or for others: "The skyscraper envelope is
not ethical, beautiful or permanent. It is a commercial
exploit or a mere expedient. It has no higher ideal of unity
than commercial success" (2). But then he couldn't have
imagined the impact of today's commercial shopping malls and
their decors, the complacent ersatz communities overshadowed
by towers.

Guy Debord, the radical French writer, attacked Le Corbusier
in 1954 for seeking to do away with the street and confine
people to towers. Debord thought architecture should be a
positive force in the community, intimately engaging with our
capacities for play and for knowledge (3). He went on to
develop the concepts of psycho-geography and unitary
urbanism, and criticised the cold geometry underlying modern
monumental urbanism and its towers and blocks.

The Chinese urban planner Zhuo Jian has counted 7,000
high-rise buildings in Shanghai; 20 of them exceed 200
metres. He has warned of ground subsidence of several
centimetres a year. Other experts have shown that tower
blocks are energy-intensive to construct (the manufacture of
sophisticated glass and steel demands enormous resources).
Nor are they cheap to maintain, with air conditioning, lifts
and central floorplate lighting - though alternative
techniques have been proposed, such as Jacques Ferrier's
energy-generating Hypergreen model. Critics point to the
short 20-year lifespan of a product that is costly and ill
suited to multi-functional requirements - how can
universities, libraries, luxury apartments and 5-star hotels
lodge under the same roof, given the disparities of activity
and clientele?

In Paris, the Seine embankment, the skyscraper residences in
the Olympiades and Flandres tower blocks, the Italie 2
shopping complex and the Montparnasse tower (1973, 209m)
don't encourage high-rise construction and platform urbanism.
In 2003 63% of Parisians didn't like high-rise buildings. In
1977 the authorities had set a 37-metre limit on the height
of new projects, but in June 2006 architects identified 17
sites in Paris suitable for towers of up to 150 metres or
17-storey residential blocks. The city council chose three
for further study in January 2007 (Porte de La Chapelle,
Bercy-Poniatowski and Masséna-Bruneseau) and 12 teams entered
proposals for towers on inhospitable terrain surrounded by
noisy and polluting infrastructure. Most were careful in
their design of green and public spaces, and paid attention
to neighbourhoods and public transport. Even so, they
neglected the impact of the towers on wind speed, light and
social nuisance; and the energy costs of construction.

The debate over aesthetics has barely started. There are many
splendid creations that beautify the skyline and grace their
location - who has not been impressed by the vertical beauty
of New York or Chicago? Yet no tower, however impressive,
should be imposed on a landscape without regard for its
environment - the network of streets and open spaces, public
transport, the impact of its scale on the buildings around
it, and its interplay with the facades and green spaces
below. Towers are anti-social - no wonder they are the
location for disaster movies.

If architects were to focus their skills on the pursuit of
more intelligent and sustainable urban environments, the
results would be less alienating: there is a need for
existential quality. Urban architecture is about people,
place and city features that affect the people who live there
(for example, street lighting). We should be cultivating much
more diversity in our urban landscapes.
________________________________________________________

Thierry Paquot is a philosopher and lecturer on urban issues,
author of Petit manifeste pour une écologie existentielle,
Bourin Éditeur, Paris, 2007, and editor of the journal
Urbanisme

(1) Paul Virilio, City of Panic, Berg, Oxford, 2004.

(2) Frank Lloyd Wright, "The Tyranny of the Skyscraper" in
Modern Architecture, Princeton University Press, Princeton,
1931.

(3) Debord in Potlatch, no 5, 20 July 1954.



Translated by Robert Corner

The imperative as an alternative

Amit Bhaduri
Seminar, February 2008

ARE SEZs necessary to ensure that the Indian economy stays on a high growth path, generating economic development in the process as well? This essay argues that such is not the case at all.

Developing countries are today confronted by a serious dilemma. In the current phase, the emerging rules of globalization are increasingly occupying the policy space of the nation-state. And yet, the global rules of the game are flawed, and biased in favour of the richer countries, especially the United States. The dilemma arises because the developing countries tend to feel that there is no alternative to accepting globalization in its present form, the so-called TINA syndrome of a unipolar world dominated by the United States (US). They do not realize that they can hardly rely on the national interests of this superpower to further their own developmental objectives. A couple of well-known examples illustrate this point.

To start with, consider world trade. Fairer global trade in agricultural commodities, without open or hidden subsidies to farmers in richer countries, is required not merely for a freer trade regime; it also affects the poorest one billion people in the world as most of them are connected directly or indirectly to agricultural activities in the rural areas of developing countries. There is hardly any other trade-related example with greater compatibility between a more efficient international price mechanism operating through freer trade, and greater global equality and economic justice. And yet, international negotiations governed by the corporate interests in the richer nations reduced global rule-making recently to a ‘tit-for-tat’ strategy that led to a breakdown in negotiations, and the tendency to impose policies decided by the richer and more powerful nations.

There are other examples of imposed rather than negotiated policies. Both the Bretton-Woods institutions, namely the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank, manipulate economic policy in the developing countries through their standard pro-market loan ‘conditionalities’. In defence of imposing pro-market conditionalities on developing countries, both these institutions place a great deal of emphasis on the principle of accountability to the market. Ironically, however, they themselves remain totally unaccountable for their performance and recommendations, no matter whether an economic collapse occurs in Argentina under their guidance, or an acute financial crisis erupts in East Asia (the only country to escape largely its adverse consequences was Malaysia, which went openly against the IMF prescriptions), or years of stagnation continue despite their recommended large-scale IMF-World Bank sponsored liberalization in sub-Saharan Africa. More blatantly, the presidents of the World Bank are chosen from the US, by the US, for the US, in the name of global development.

The power of imposing rules, which the rich nations have over the poor nations, arises to a large extent from several historically inherited structural asymmetries underlying the present world capitalist system on which is premised the current process of globalization. Without identifying them clearly, it would appear that this process of globalization led by the interests of the rich is a natural phenomenon, somewhat like an earthquake or a drought, consequences that have to be accepted because they cannot be controlled. We would be in a better position to integrate strategically with the global economy to our advantage, instead of meekly submitting to it, if we understand these structural asymmetries.

To begin with, the most fundamental asymmetry in the world economy arises today from the freedom of movement of capital, especially financial capital on one hand, and the restrictions on the movement of labour on the other, especially unskilled labour from developing countries. Despite vast improvements in travel and communications technology, available estimates suggest that labour migration as a proportion of the total world population has been lower in the current phase (approximately 1973 to date) compared to the earlier phase of globalization (approximately 1870-1913).

On a rough reckoning, about one in six persons crossed national borders for employment or livelihood between 1860 and 1900. They went as indentured labour from China and India, as colonial settlers from Europe to North, Central and South America, and to Australia. Over a comparable period of nearly five decades of the current phase of globalization, not more than one in seven persons migrated. Contrast this relatively sluggish movement of labour with the movements of capital, especially financial capital during the current phase of globalization. Rough estimates available from the Bank of International Settlements suggest that the annual volume of private trade in foreign exchange is about 450 trillion dollars, almost nine times the volume of world GDP. Of this, less than two per cent is accounted for by trade in goods and services, and even if one adds all direct foreign investment it would still be well below four per cent. So, purely financial transactions account annually for over eight times the world GDP. (By contrast, in the era of regulated finance in the early 1970s, only about 10% of all international transactions were financial.)

A few days of hostile private trade in the foreign exchange market can wipe out the entire foreign reserve of all the central banks in the world. The defining characteristic of the current phase of globalization has become this overwhelming dominance of private trade in finance. The world has not seen anything like this before.

The rise to ascendancy of international finance started with successive waves of liberalization of the major capital markets of the advanced capitalist countries starting around mid-1970s, and assumed irresistible momentum by early 1980s. The entire process was further stimulated by the internet boom of the 1990s and by rapid advances in telecommunications technology. Although little explicit note is taken of its implications in public discussions and government pronouncements, its imprint has been deep on the pace and pattern of world development in general, and Indian development in particular.

Economic policies are increasingly formulated by the Indian government with a view to appease the sentiments of financial markets. The English language media, especially the electronic media that shape Indian middle-class opinion, tend to behave as if the daily fluctuations of the stock market provide a barometer of the health of the real economy. However, the Indian stock market is minuscule in relation to the vast size of global private trade in foreign exchange mentioned earlier. The rupee and Indian stocks can easily be set into an uncontrollable downward spiral by a few large international players speculating against some Indian stocks or the rupee.

This is not at all fanciful. Recall how Dalal Street nosedived immediately after the 2004 general election results, because a few large, mostly foreign institutional investors, began to withdraw from the Indian capital market fearing that a coalition government supported by the left will be unfriendly towards private businesses. However, as soon as the UPA government named its top economic team, a trio of the prime minister, the finance minister and the deputy chairman of the planning commission, all known for their extreme pro-market and corporate-friendly outlook, the stock markets began to stabilize in no time.

Nothing had changed about ground realities of the Indian economy in those few weeks, except that international finance capital needed political assurances. In the process, the future course of economic policies of the country was set, and the left sufficiently tamed as its subsequent economic policies are showing.

This story would remain incomplete for India, as for other developing countries, if we miss the critical role of the IMF and the World Bank. Since those two institutions are in a pivotal position to influence the perception of private foreign investors like multinational corporations, banks and other financial institutions about a country’s investment climate, they exert a significant influence on financial markets. If the economic policies of a government are favourable to the corporations, it generally gets a good chit from the IMF and the World Bank, encouraging capital to flow in to stimulate the stock market. With an unfavourable signal from those institutions, the government runs the risk of capital flying out in a destabilizing manner.

This, not merely free trade, is the name of the financial game under globalization. The IMF, the World Bank and all those suffering from the TINA syndrome would like us to believe this is indeed the only game in town! Under pressure from the Bretton-Woods institutions, India passed a Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act (FRBM) in 2003 which prevents the government from spending more in areas like elementary education, expanding rural employment guarantee or making it effective by strengthening decentralization of the panchayat system through adequate fiscal autonomy. Tribals and peasants are evicted from lands with little compensation and their livelihoods destroyed to improve the ‘investment climate’.

It is becoming increasingly apparent that in the name of development policies of developmental terrorism on the poor are being pursued. It might deliver high growth in the short term, but it is growth without a democratic content. It does not reach the poor citizens of India who need to benefit most from the process of growth. This is why each and every government that has been following this sort of policy gets showered with the approval of the corporate sector, the IMF and the World Bank, and even the upper middle class, but loses the general election.

The Congress government under the then Prime Minister Narasimha Rao with Manmohan Singh as its finance minister spearheading economic reforms lost the general election. Manmohan Singh personally failed to win a seat. The BJP-led coalition crashed in the 2004 general election with its ‘Shining India’ slogan; it did especially badly in Andhra which was shining under the glow of IT industries. There is no reason to believe that things would be any different next time. However, this would require going against the hidden script of globalization by upsetting the alliance between large domestic industrial houses, multinational corporations and banks including the IMF and the WB, and a pliable domestic government irrespective of its political label.

The second important asymmetry in the current phase of globalization arises from the increasingly freer flow of trade in goods and services on the one hand, and the growing restriction on the transfer of knowledge and technology embodied in the production of those goods and services on the other. In the emerging regime of Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), all developing countries, including India, find it increasingly difficult to learn and adopt the production technology involved in the goods and services they import. The asymmetry of the emerging trade regime has been characterized by freer trade in goods and services coupled with greater restrictions on the flow of productive knowledge.

Thus, the more ‘liberalized’ trade regime of the World Trade Organization (WTO) puts India under increasing pressure to import goods and services rather than produce them at home. It is conveniently forgotten that international trade has been the vehicle for learning the technology embodied in the traded goods and new products throughout history. This learning process involved through international trade may well be the most important dynamic gains from freer trade, far outweighing the static gains of existing comparative advantage.

By treating knowledge more and more as simply a privately tradable commodity, the current trade regime shows its bias towards corporations as the generator of knowledge who should be handsomely rewarded, but forgets the importance of other sources of knowledge like traditional community-based knowledge to the detriment of many indigenous communities. This, however, does not stop globally powerful drug giants from engaging in biopiracy by relying precisely on the knowledge of herbs held by tribal communities of this country!

It is in this context of freer trade in goods and services that the economic consequence of globalization in terms of the increased relative importance of the external vis-à-vis the internal or domestic market needs to be examined. It has influenced thinking on macroeconomic policy in a way which is seldom highlighted. It emphasizes the importance of reducing the costs of production through more efficient supply-side policies for increasing the international competitiveness of the national economy, but ignores the problem of creating adequate purchasing power and aggregate demand through relative neglect of the domestic market.

This shift of emphasis from domestic demand to international cost competitiveness raises concerns about labour market ‘flexibility’ and various forms of wage restraint. Lower wages tend to depress the unit cost of production, but also the consumption demand from wage income. Consequently, unless either higher luxury consumption, investment or increased export surplus makes up for that reduction in consumption demand in a regime of investment or export-led growth, insufficient aggregate demand at home would become the binding constraint on development.

Similarly, the emphasis on increasing output (value added) per worker or labour productivity (to reduce labour cost of business) and using this as a tool for enhancing international competitiveness has its downside. Attention focused only on labour productivity separates it from the level of employment in the economy. Thus total output would decrease despite an increase in productivity, if the percentage decrease in the level of employment exceeds the increase in labour productivity. Consequently, the corporate strategy of ‘downsizing’ the labour force to create a ‘lean and efficient corporation’ for increasing market share might turn out to be good for a particular corporation, but macro-economically counterproductive if many corporations do it simultaneously with shrinking of total supply, and of the size of the domestic market.

Such policies of reducing unit cost in search of greater efficiency are effective on the microeconomic scale of a single corporation, but counterproductive on the macroeconomic scale due to their effect of depressing aggregate demand. The blurring of this distinction between micro-level and macro-level efficiency, typical of the corporate ideology, gives rise to many ‘fallacies of composition’ in macroeconomic policy by assuming that the individual microeconomic ‘parts’ have the same properties as the ‘whole’ macroeconomic system. In actual fact, the whole is different from the sum of the parts.

The third asymmetry arises in the current phase of globalization from the role assigned to the state in monitoring and regulating economic activities. The market-oriented neo-liberal philosophy intends to curb the role of the state as an economic actor, but gives rise to an almost schizophrenic view of the capabilities of the state. It is usually claimed that the state cannot be trusted with expansionary monetary and fiscal policies (e.g. FRBM Act of 2003 mentioned earlier) because it has an inbuilt tendency to be financially irresponsible. At the same time, however, the same state is relied upon to undertake far more complex financial tasks like extending the scope of the market though privatization without corruption, regulating the stock exchange, etc. This schizophrenic view about its capabilities is rooted in denying the state its developmental and distributive role, but using it to promote the reach of the multinational corporations through measures like privatization.

This also poses the most serious challenge to our democratic form of government. It leads in the case of India to the most fundamental asymmetry in the relation between our political democracy and the market mechanism. In neo-liberal philosophy, the free market and democracy are considered mutually reinforcing, as both extend the scope of individual choice. And yet, the types of freedom granted by the market economy and political democracy are often in conflict in developing countries. The democratic principle of ‘one-adult-one-vote’ coexists rather uneasily with the free market philosophy that the rich, with greater purchasing power, would have more ‘votes’ than the poor in the marketplace.

This asymmetry becomes even more acute when with greater inequality in the distribution of income a larger proportion of the poor have political voting rights, but are economically without a ‘voice’ in the market. In these circumstances, the democratic form of government comes under increasing strain if too much freedom is granted to the market. Yet, the process of globalization relentlessly generates a situation in which national governments (having already succumbed) end up having little control over the free play of global market forces as they impinge on their own country.

As a matter of fact the history of the relation between economic development and democracy has been far more complex than the currently fashionable ‘political correctness’ would have us believe. Historically, the per capita income of the western countries had to reach a minimum of 2000 dollar per capita per year before anything close to universal suffrage was granted. This was a high level compared to India’s 200-250 dollars around the time of our first general election in 1952 (measured in 1999 at Purchasing Power Parity or PPP calculation).

It is an unparalleled achievement in recorded history that political democracy in India has been sustained at that level of poverty despite the tremendous diversity of the country. This also poses the most serious challenge to our democratic form of government. It must control the excesses of globalization and domination by corporations of our economy. Our democracy has to ensure that the process of growth is not corporate-driven, but is decentralized and led by rural employment, in order to allow for the widest participation of our citizens. Only then will the wealth created by growth be fairly shared, and growth itself will have a democratic content. It will be growth of wealth created by the people, for the people. This compulsion of our time can neither be met by globalization, nor by corporate-led growth supported by the government. Unfortunately neither the right nor the left seem to have woken up to this challenge for a pattern of development that gives dignity to all citizens.

If multiparty parliamentary democracy means giving people a wide range of political choices, we have it in plenty in India. However, if we have to also choose the content in critical areas of economic policy there is hardly any choice left. A marked convergence among political parties is taking place, less apparent in their rhetoric, but unmistakably clear in their actions. One could have believed that this is the result of the compromises of coalition politics at the centre. But when the same thing happens at the level of states, and political parties of different labels follow with equal vengeance the same economic course, no room is left even for illusions.

Grand terms like ‘growth’, ‘industrialization’, and ‘development’ are used by politicians with abandon these days to hide the poverty of their economics and politics. But the central question remains unanswered. If a high rate of growth of a particular sort necessarily entails a certain type of industrialization, is this industrialization synonymous with development?

The type of industrialization India is experiencing with recent high growth has three characteristics that are unmistakably neo-liberal. First, it is led by corporations. Second, they are mostly private corporations. Third, the role that the government plays at the central and at the state level is that of a promoter, an agent of private corporations, not one of a regulator. All parliamentary political parties seem to agree. We are repeatedly told that sacrifice is needed for this industrialization, but it is conveniently left untold that the sacrifice must be borne by those who are least capable of bearing it, the poor and the most marginalized sections of society. The rich corporations need not sacrifice. Instead, they are subsidized by the governments. The estimated subsidy for the Tatas in Singur, West Bengal is over Rs 850 crore for an investment of Rs 1000 crore. Similar deals are said to have been cut by the other big industrialists for SEZs and other projects.

The traditional political differences have been homogenized into a neo-liberal consensus. Insofar as the traditional left is concerned, first Singur and then Nandigram drove home the point that many of the left politicians are not that different from the ‘dream team’ of economic policy-makers at the Centre who favour the World Bank, the IMF and the Asian Development Bank. The cultural nationalists of the Hindutva variety violently uphold their culture when it comes to Ram Mandir and ‘Vande Mataram’, but surrender willingly to foreign multinationals. The political doubletalk everywhere is amazing.

Congress has a remarkably short memory about the Sikh massacre of 1984. The left parties rightly breathe fire about the Gujarat massacre of 2002, while BJP covers it up with false propaganda and manipulation of the state machinery. When Nandigram massacres happened in 2007 and Advani compared it with Jallianwala Bagh, conveniently forgetting Gujarat, CPM leaders and some of the supportive intellectuals called it an unfortunate incident that happened accidentally. The unwarranted shooting of 13 tribals in Kalinganagar in 2006 by the police bears an uncanny parallel. The tribals were refusing to hand over their land to the same Tatas in Kalinganagar, just as in Singur and Nandigram the peasants have been resisting. Should we be erecting a defence of empty words to say how different Navin Patnaik is from Buddhadeb Bhattacharya only because they go by different political labels? It is evident from a chronological survey of field reports from Kalinganagar and Nandigram that these were premeditated actions by the state authorities to test the waters and see how far they can go in the service of large corporations.

In this world of neo-liberal harmony, parties of different shades insist that corporate-style industrialization with the state as its agent is our only option. At the same time, the Indian polity with an increasingly inequitable economy thrives in the name of high growth, industrialization and ‘development’, working ruthlessly against the poor majority. A spectre of despair and popular anger haunts all corners of the country now. Farmers are committing suicide in thousands, especially in Maharashtra, Andhra Pradesh and Punjab because the government wants to usher in a new type of commercial, industrialized agriculture under WTO, with expensive inputs supplied by multinationals, but without any subsidy or an appropriate price for their produce.

In Chhattisgarh, in the name of fighting extremism, tribals are being forcibly evacuated in thousands from their villages under Salwa Judum, to be huddled in Vietnam-style concentration camps while the corporations eye greedily their land, rich in mineral resources. The poorest, though richest in natural resources, are kept down by denying them what belongs to them by birth.

Since land is a state subject according to the Constitution of India, the question of land acquisition, and the degree of coercion used thereby, is largely the prerogative of the state government. This is where the political hypocrisy is particularly evident, and the rhetoric about centre-state division of power cannot hide it. Land is being acquired by various state governments in a competitive race-to-the-bottom in order to win the favour of the big corporations. The argument goes, ‘If we in West Bengal do not do it, Uttarakhand will do it’ or, ‘We can be more ferocious than Orissa in pleasing the Tatas or the Jindals or whoever else.’ This has legal and moral encouragement from the central government, but the state government has full constitutional power not to oblige.

Land is being acquired in different guises for mining, industry, power projects, large estates and IT parks and, most recently for special economic zones (SEZ) under the ‘eminent domain’ clause of the Land Acquisition Act (1894), which allows the state to override private property right in land in the ‘public interest’. Land, the primary source of livelihood in the agrarian economy, includes as per the act, ‘everything’ attached to land – water, minerals. Therefore, it becomes the most obvious case of coercive transfer of resources from common people (for whom land and the resource base is not mere property but livelihood) to private corporations. Using the same old act since the British days, amended in 1984, land acquisition is carried out to serve corporate interest, destroy livelihoods, and displace people.

It is often said there are invariably gainers and losers in such economic processes, which the economist Jospeh Schumpeter had long ago captured with the phrase ‘creative destruction’. However, in the present context this is a misleading half-truth. If such creative destruction was just a part of the normal process of capitalistic development, it would have been unnecessary for the state to intervene in the guise of ‘public interest’ on behalf of private corporations. It involves a transaction between two private parties, namely the corporation and the landowning peasants, without a level-playing field. The function of the state should be to at least ensure that this transaction is voluntary, particularly because one party in the transaction is economically far weaker. This would mean that the corporations would acquire land at a price at which the peasants are willing to part voluntarily with their land, either individually or through collective decisions, the latter being especially relevant in the case of tribal land.

Instead, what has been happening is that the state is using force and violence under a cloak of secrecy despite the Right to Information Act. Although the SEZ scheme has the most pronounced pro-corporate bias, the difference between acquiring SEZ land in Nandigram, and the land for the Tata-Fiat joint venture in Singur is one of legal nicety, not of relevance insofar as those who derive livelihood from that land are concerned. And, even after Nandigram, what most parties, including the CPM have to recommend is not the scrapping of SEZ altogether, but restricting its maximum size and other minor changes!

Although land is the most visible symbol of transfer of resources to the corporations, the problem goes deeper. The bias against the poor in policy-making is both direct and indirect. The direct bias is visible in plan allocation. Despite 60% or more of our working population depending on agriculture, all the recent five year plans under different governments have allocated less than five per cent of planned investment to agriculture. The indirect bias operates pervasively through a pattern of consumption and production promoted by the state. Mammoth projects create the impression of urban gloss, with fancy express-ways, underground metros, flyovers etc. at public cost.

We take it for granted that many of these public utilities are essential for efficiency, saving time in travelling, improving the quality of life, even for attracting investment. These arguments are not false, but one-sided. We need, even more desperately, higher efficiency and better quality of life in rural India where the majority lives. In the metropolitan area, we need infrastructure to ensure basic amenities to the most needy. Manhattan-like world-class cities are set as our goals, when 25% to 60% of the urban population lives a subhuman existence in slums. So why this bias, and whom does it benefit? It certainly benefits the urban elite population, and leads to uncontrolled urbanization and mega cities with growing hunger for energy, water and other resources. Slums are cleared without providing resettlement options, poverty banished only from sight. Millions suffer.

This large-scale destruction of livelihoods of both urban and rural communities is only the surface phenomenon. The modes of transport we are creating with more flyovers for cars (including Tatas’ people’s car), the type of shopping or housing complexes we are promoting are not merely iniquitous. They are far more polluting and resource and energy-intensive, and the majority of our ordinary citizens who do not consume them also have to pay directly or indirectly for this pattern of consumption. This is why farmers get less water, are starved of electricity in critical periods and clean drinking water or proper sanitation is a luxury in villages.

The idea that industry is more efficient than agriculture is largely because of this pronounced bias against agriculture and the poor. With almost two-thirds of our work force in agriculture producing under one-fourth of national output, output per worker in agriculture is about 40 per cent of national average. In contrast, industry and services have a labour productivity double the national average. This is also an old game of attributing ‘values’ to selected products and services, so that higher growth is achieved by transferring more and more resources to the high productivity sector, and by favouring large corporations which organize this pattern of production for privileged India. The other (much larger) India watches in despair and anger, while many have no choice but to commit suicide. Must we not strive for an economic alternative on the basis of a new politics?

An economic alternative stimulating another kind of development is feasible. Elements of it exist even in the present political-economic system. Very briefly, it has to be based on three basic premises. First, we must learn to rely far more on the internal rather than the external market. The biggest driving force of the internal market is the purchasing power of the ordinary people derived from employment growth. India’s record on this score has been dismal in recent years. An eight per cent growth in output has been accompanied by barely one per cent growth in regular employment, and increase in irregular or ancillary employment is marked by flexible contracts loaded against the worker, with insecurity and overcrowding of infrastructure.

It is foolish to expect that corporate-led growth can do better on the employment front, because corporations are in the game of making profit by cutting costs, including labour costs. And the more we accept globalization unconditionally, the stronger would be the relative importance of the external over the internal market. This means cutting labour costs in order to increase exports will become even more pressing. Primacy to exports also means priorities in production going against the needs of the population here. Growth of the internal market through rapid employment growth, therefore, requires a far more selective approach to globalization.

Second, economic growth must be the outcome of employment growth, not the other way round and the former should never be at the cost of the latter. Employment growth in the 1980s was twice of what it is now, even though the growth rate of GDP was a little more than half of what it is today. Our benchmark should be a time-bound programme for full employment. How much the growth in employment contributes to growth in output depends naturally on how productively labour can be employed. India has performed poorly in this respect. The main reason is a bureaucratized system of central control which kills local initiative. We have to start at the opposite end of socialist orthodoxy, not by accepting neo-liberalism, but by forging a new combination altogether.

On the one hand, we have to get out of the grip of corporate-led industrialization by making agriculture and the rural economy the centre of economic dynamism; on the other, we have to break the grip of current centralized bureaucratic decision-making. This can be done by extending the present national employment guarantee scheme to an ambitious time-bound full employment programme. It will involve delegating much of the decision-making power to the panchayats and local bodies to identify, formulate and execute local employment-generating productive projects.

A precondition for this is local control over local resources related to land, and maximum fiscal autonomy for the panchayats. Even the Constitution, through Article 243, provided for a Finance Commission to support and ensure that village/ward-level local bodies become financially viable. It was to be appointed in 1993. No government, central or state, followed this up seriously. The record of Kerala has been the best while that of West Bengal government has been among the worst.

Acknowledging that the Left Front played a role in getting NREGA enacted, it is shocking that only 14 per cent of the money allotted in the poorest Bengal district of Purulia for employment guarantee was spent until December 2006, more than half the money of employment guarantee provided by the Centre remaining unspent in the state. Not more than 16 days of employment was provided, while the legal and financial provision allows for 100 days. (Reports from other states too show a similar situation with an exception in certain areas). If the governments had shown the same zeal in making a success of employment guarantee as they have shown in acquiring land from the unwilling peasants, we would have taken at least the first step towards a genuine process of development. The irony is that such an approach would be a political success at the polls. Yet, the path is not being followed!

Finally, there is the question of finance. Where would the money come from for such an ambitious employment programme, and how to make sure it is spent effectively? The Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act (2003) which ties the hands of the government in spending money for most pressing needs like employment guarantee must be scrapped. With this act the Centre pushes privatization to raise money, denies basic health and educational expenditure, and restricts the role of public policy in the name of financial discipline. This suits well the IMF, the World Bank, and the corporations who want the state to promote, not regulate them.

This is where the left should have its biggest battle, and insist that money that is needed for employment, basic education, health and social security of the unorganized workers must be found within our means, if necessary by revising this law. Its own policy imagination failing, it went along instead with the neo-liberal economic ideology with only a whimper of initial protest, ultimately succumbing to corporate-led industrialization. A recent statement by a veteran left leader regarding the inevitability of capitalism is a case in point.

To ensure fiscal autonomy for local bodies, their budget can be kept in a separate account in nationalized banks with a credit line extended to panchayats. This would avoid duplication of institutions, while a system of mutual check and balance between the panchayats and the local branch of nationalized banks can be devised based on their performance as borrowers and lenders. Banks would lend the next round only if the previous project succeeds, and panchayats can borrow the next round only if the money is well-spent. It is this mutuality of interest which has to be strengthened over time in creating the new form of sustained financing for development.

Regardless of whether the growth is 8 or 10 per cent, these measures would initiate a process that empowers the poor, imparting a genuine democratic and participatory content to India’s development. If our political parties, policy-makers and bureaucrats can reach a consensus and display the same collective commitment to the participatory approach outlined in this essay that they have hitherto shown in order to achieve corporate-led high ‘growth at any cost’, at least five desirable goals of development in the country can be attained.

First, easy as it might sound, unemployment and poverty can be eliminated within the foreseeable future. Second, by putting purchasing power in the hands of the hitherto destitute, the domestic market for industrial products and basic needs can be developed, creating a fresh source of healthy growth for industry and the macroeconomy. Third, through the public works programmes that the rural poor will execute, infrastructure (like roads, irrigation, etc.) can be strengthened and expanded. Fourth, priority environmental projects (such as watershed development, afforestation, groundwater recharge and soil conservation) can be undertaken to stem and reverse the worsening ecological crisis the country will face in the approaching future. Finally, by generating employment in the countryside the policy will reverse the flow of distress migrants to the cities (saddled as they already are with burdened infrastructure).

SEZs are not needed to find such a growth-and-development path. In fact, it is difficult to conceive of a single policy which can meet so many desirable goals at one stroke. There are times in history when what is desirable is also necessary and imperative. The alternative to destructive, socially and environmentally destabilizing growth stares us in the face. Unless the reforms inaugurated in 1991 are radically reformed and humanized by a fresh approach, we may be entering a period of great political and social turmoil, courting environmental disasters in the process. The question is: can we as a citizenry commit ourselves to the urgent task at hand?